The rise and fall of great powers is stochastic

By Razib Khan | January 20, 2011 12:47 pm

ResearchBlogging.orgLong time readers know well my fascination with quantitative history. In particular, cliometrics and cliodynamics. These are fields which attempt to measure and model human historical phenomena and processes. Cliometrics is a well established field, insofar as it is a subset of economic history. But cliodynamics is new on the scene. At the heart of cliodynamics is the quantitative ecologist Peter Turchin. I highly recommend his readable series of books, Historical Dynamics, War and Peace and War, and Secular Cycles. Also, see my reviews of the first two books.

With that, I am rather excited by the debut of Cliodynamics: The Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History. Here’s the description of the brief of the field and the journal:

‘Cliodynamics’ is a transdisciplinary area of research integrating historical macrosociology, economic history/cliometrics, mathematical modeling of long-term social processes, and the construction and analysis of historical databases. Cliodynamics: The Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History is an international peer-reviewed web-based/free-access journal that will publish original articles advancing the state of theoretical knowledge in this discipline. ‘Theory’ in the broadest sense includes general principles that explain the functioning and dynamics of historical societies and models, usually formulated as mathematical equations or computer algorithms. It also has empirical content that deals with discovering general empirical patterns, determining empirical adequacy of key assumptions made by models, and testing theoretical predictions with the data from actual historical societies. A mature, or ‘developed theory,’ thus, integrates models with data; the main goal of Cliodynamics is to facilitate progress towards such theory in history.

The first issue has an article by Sergey Gavrilets, David G. Anderson, and Peter Turchin. Gavrilets is a familiar face. I know him from his work in evolutionary theory. The paper itself is a readable and plausible model of how “medium scale” societies rise and fall through conflict and consolidation. Basically the stage of human society described in Laurence Keely’s seminal War Before Civilization; after agriculture, but before major literate state systems. Their basic method is to take a mathematical model with a tractable number of plausible parameters and run simulations which give one a sense of how it changes dependent variables of interest. Polities were modeled as being circumscribed hexagons; so they had six neighbors (instead of four which would be the case if they were squares). The area modeled had an “edge,” and polities can exist in a flat hierarchical structure, or eventually aggregate so they exhibit rank order. Additionally, polities varied by economic productivity. Finally, there was a temporal aspect in that there was a potential conflict per generation where the probability of success was conditional upon the strength of the polity. Being more powerful increase the probability of victory, but does not guarantee it. Flukes do happen. The full model can be found in the paper, which is open access. The math isn’t totally opaque, so I’m really not going to distill it down. You can swallow it whole. Rather, let’s look at the list of parameters and statistics:


Most of the above variables are pretty straightforward. You should know that “complexity” refers to the levels of structure above the independent village. Presumably larger polities will have more complex structures, because they have to. Here’s a figure which shows the dependency of the statistics over time on α, the scaling exponent. α = 2 a quadratic, while α = 1 linear. The area of a square grows as a quadratic function. In other words, there are greater gains to to the variable than a linear increase.

As you can see, maximum complexity and polity size seems to be strongly contingent upon the scaling exponent. This makes sense: the powerful get more powerful when the differentials are less swamped out by noise. Remember that the probability of victory in war is dependent in part on the scaling exponent, so when you increase the rate of victory as a function of greater power, you can have longer strings of “wins,” and so more aggregation.

The table to the left shows the big outcomes from their simulations. I’ve underlined what you need to focus on. You can see that α and τ have the big effects on the properties of the system in terms of how they vary over time. Basically the greater returns there are on power differentials, the more large polities will emerge and flourish. This is intuitively obvious. Second, the other major factor which influences the growth and flourishing of large and complex polities seems to be the time of rule of a given chief. The other factors seem less important when it comes to maximum size or complexity, which are probably the two statistics of major interest to us.

So does this tell us something we don’t know? Qualitatively we know this already. The authors choose to focus on pre-Columbian North American societies as well as Sub-Saharan African and Oceanian ones. But they do give the nod to the “big name” civilizations too, which aren’t really modeled here because their scale and complexity is outside of the purview of the parameters given here. To anyone who knows history the importance of the returns to asymmetric power and length of leadership are qualitatively obvious. In the first case, it seems almost tautological that if you reduce the “noise” in wars, and simply allow for victory to go to those who should win “on paper,” there would be a “winner take all” dynamic. Small initial differences could much more quickly snowball into large differences. In some ways this is like evolution; increase population size and selection becomes more efficacious vis-a-vis stochastic forces (drift remains powerful to the same extent, as per neutral theory, selection simply has a larger footprint).

But what about the second variable? It is descriptively a well known fact that polities of massive scope and longevity tend to have a run of long-lived rulers at their inception. Consider the reigns of Augustus and Tiberius for Rome. Akbar, Jehangir, Shah Jahan and Aurangzeb for the Mughals. Kangxi and Qianlong for the Ching.  Taizong and Xuanzong of the Tang. And so on. The question though is: are these long reigns the chicken or the egg? In other words, is the length of the reigns at the beginning of a political order simply a function of the endogenous factors which give rise to political units? Or does the length of rule itself impact the nature of the political system? These results seem to point to a causal role for the length of rule. I find this plausible. In the pre-modern era the death of even elites was to some extent a much more random affair than today. The death of Edward VI of England during his teenage years probably had a huge impact on the future trajectory of the culture of the British nation. That death occurred simply through an act of God in the era before modern medicine. Therefore, one of the stochastic aspects of polity size in the pre-modern era was probably simply the necessity for a random run of political leaders who did not die of illness (the second century famously had a run of Roman emperors who had no male heirs, so they adopted competent successors).

The Sui-Tang dynasty of China perhaps hints at a dynamic where structural forces set the preconditions for the emergence of a large and stable polity, but personal rule means that there is still an element of stochasticity in terms of when the rise to power of that polity will occur. There were several “false starts” in the interregnum between the fall of the Latter Han and the rise of the Sui-Tang. This chaotic period was exceptionally long by the standards of later Chinese history.  One model, which I find plausible, is that the institutions of Chinese society became more robust, and allowed for more rapid re-integrations after the collapse. But another model could be that the long period between the Latter Han and the Sui-Tang was simply due to a series of long odds. In other words, not only are large and complex political systems due to chance contingent upon the length of reigns, the perpetuation of fragmentation is also the inverse of that result.

Finally, I think of the points that the authors are trying to make needs to be emphasized:

Our model provides theoretical support for a view that the formation of complex polities is “a predictable response to certain specific cultural, demographic and ecological conditions”…Conditions explicitly accounted by our model include warfare, circumscription, variation in productivity between different local communities, ability to generate surpluses, ability to delegate power, and restrictions on the growth of polities due to scalar stress. Once these conditions are present within a particular geographic area, the model predicts rapid formation of hierarchically organized competing polities partitioning available space.

A striking feature of the model output is the fluid nature of “significant” polities, which continuously go through stochastic cycles of growth (both in size and complexity) and collapse. Growth is driven by successful warfare whereas collapse results from defeat in warfare, rebellion of subchiefs, or fragmentation following the death of the paramount chief. The lifetime of chiefdoms observed in our simulation – a few generations – is comparable to those identified by archaeological studies…The model suggests that the rapid collapse of chiefdoms can occur even without environmental perturbations (e.g., drought) or overpopulation.

First, the model has elements of randomness, and, determinism. Complex societies naturally arise given particular structural preconditions, but the long term dynamics exhibit stochasticity. Second, that stochasticity may be a due to endogenous parameters within the system. In other words, randomness in long term dynamcis may not be due to an outside “shock,” like climate change or disease. Rather, it may simply be due to the fact that societies are complex systems which oscillate around equilibriums.

Citation: Gavrilets, Sergey, David G. Anderson, & Peter Turchin (2011). Cycling in the Complexity of Early Societies Cliodynamics: The Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History

CATEGORIZED UNDER: Culture, History
  • http://washparkprophet.blogspot.com ohwilleke

    The novel Eifelheim (2006), by Michael Flynn (which is mediocre as literature but has lots of good descriptions of scientifc ideas in it), features a protagonist who uses this kind of mathematical modeling of hexagonal geographical units with a few simple mathematical features as the starting point for it narrative — a mysterious group of hexagons in part of Germany that the model insists should be home to a major city but hasn’t been for a thousand plus years and is shrouded in legends that hint at why this might be so.

  • DK

    These results seem to point to a causal role for the length of rule.

    They don’t. They are simply a self-fulfilling prophecy. You get back what you built into the model. In this case a death of chief stipulates random rise of independent chiefdoms without a war. Since for all other events independence requires a war, little wonder then that frequency of death becomes very important.

    The model suggests that the rapid collapse of chiefdoms can occur even without environmental perturbations (e.g., drought) or overpopulation.

    I think they actually mean “without *large-scale* environmental perturbations”. By design, the evolution of their model is driven by random environmental perturbations. Overall all of it makes sense and is entirely plausible – I just don’t feel one needs any modeling to arrive to the similar conclusions that have the same level of plausibility.

  • AG

    Han dynasty must be exception. Han dynasty was one of the longest dynasty in Chinese hitory. Han founding emperor Liu Bang only lived to his 50s. The second emperor was not very long lived either. But his grandson Han Wudi (martial emperor) had long life and was also famous for his aggressive attitude toward XiongNu or Hun. After his dynasty, XiongNu started its decline. Because of Wudi’s territorial expension and military achievement, majority of Chinese speakers started identifing themself as “Han” people. Han idendity estabolished despite of all different name later dynasties.

  • http://washparkprophet.blogspot.com ohwilleke

    “They are simply a self-fulfilling prophecy. You get back what you built into the model.”

    The point of models like these are not to prove something by themselves. Instead, they allow you to identify simpler propositions to prove, which, if true, would establish that the model is right.

    For example, if the predominant way that an independent chiefdomship arises without a war is as a result of the death of chief, then we know that this kind of event will have big implications for the dynamics (a non-obvious result). Then, we can dig through the best available datat in chiefdomship societies that are documented historically to determine what historically did cause independent chiefdomships to arise. If our model assumption is supported, we get a lot more bang for our buck out of that factual discovery than we would otherwise.

    Similar garbage in, garbage out criticisms can be made of a recent contagion model of terrorism, where the key variable is the extent to which a harsh suppression of a suspected terrorist gives rise to more terrorism. If the parameters are adjusted appropriately, you can get any result you want. But, if those parameters can be given independent support, either by measuring them directly (probably with unacceptable uncertainty, but still accurately enough to narrow the possible values to a certain range) or indirectly by fitting the model to the observable data modeled as dependent variable, and the independent variable data known with certainty (e.g. number of enforcement actions).

    If you can estimate parameters and get results that fit the past data, and your data set is well behaved enough and large enough to prevent flukes and outliers from driving the fit to the data, then you can have reasonable comfort that your model will predict future outcomes at least as well as any one else can.

    In contrast, if you get a “bin” of results with a lot of good hits and a lot of wild misses, there is probably an important variable missing from the analysis.

    The key that makes any of these kinds of models work in such complex systems is that in a large universe of systems in the range of possibility where the model will be used, a small number of variables frequently drives the bulk of the total result. For example, while there are countless parts of a car design that can impact its 0 to 60 time, engine horse power alone explains most of that within the realm of typical passenger car sized internal combustion engine powered vehicles on normal roads.

    Of course, there are systems where you really do need dozens of inputs to make any reasonable predictions, but those are the exceptions and not the norm.

  • http://www.isteve.blogspot.com Steve Sailer

    Extremely long spans for rulers are probably bad, too, because stasis and decadence sets in. Ivory Coast would probably be better off today if Houphet-Boigny, who had appeared competent in his prime, hadn’t ruled into his dotage.

  • http://washparkprophet.blogspot.com ohwilleke

    When I was studying history, the trend I had seen was one of rulers who took power young being successful. Perhaps it was due to long spans of rule, perhaps not. But, it would be interesting to compare the hypothesises.

NEW ON DISCOVER
OPEN
CITIZEN SCIENCE
ADVERTISEMENT

Discover's Newsletter

Sign up to get the latest science news delivered weekly right to your inbox!

Gene Expression

This blog is about evolution, genetics, genomics and their interstices. Please beware that comments are aggressively moderated. Uncivil or churlish comments will likely get you banned immediately, so make any contribution count!

About Razib Khan

I have degrees in biology and biochemistry, a passion for genetics, history, and philosophy, and shrimp is my favorite food. In relation to nationality I'm a American Northwesterner, in politics I'm a reactionary, and as for religion I have none (I'm an atheist). If you want to know more, see the links at http://www.razib.com

ADVERTISEMENT

See More

ADVERTISEMENT

RSS Razib’s Pinboard

Edifying books

Collapse bottom bar
+

Login to your Account

X
E-mail address:
Password:
Remember me
Forgot your password?
No problem. Click here to have it e-mailed to you.

Not Registered Yet?

Register now for FREE. Registration only takes a few minutes to complete. Register now »